JUDGMENT
Bloomsbury International Limited and others
(Respondents) v Sea Fish Industry Authority and
Department for Environment, Food and Rural
Affairs (Appellant)
before
Lord Phillips, President
Lord Walker
Lady Hale
Lord Mance
Lord Collins
JUDGMENT GIVEN ON
15 June 2011
Heard on 23 and 24 March 2011
Appellant Respondents (for the 1st
,
7th and 8th)
Hugh Mercer QC Fergus Randolph QC
Tim Eicke QC
Iain Quirk
Margaret Gray
Karwan Eskerie
(Instructed by DEFRA
Law & Corporate
Services)
(Instructed by The Wilkes
Partnership)
Intervener (Sea Fish
Industry Authority)
Mark Hoskins QC
Robert Weekes
(Instructed by Treasury
Solicitor)
Page 2
LORD MANCE (with whom Lord Walker, Lady Hale and Lord Collins
agree)
Introduction
1. The Sea Fish Industry Authority (“the Authority”) is established under the
Fisheries Act 1981 with powers granted “for the purpose of promoting the
efficiency of the sea fish industry and so as to serve the interests of that industry as
a whole” (section 2(1)). For the purpose of financing its activities, the Authority
may, by regulations confirmed by ministerial order, “impose a levy on persons
engaged in the sea fish industry” (section 4(1) and (2)).
2. The issues on this appeal are, firstly, whether this power extends to
imposing a levy in respect of sea fish or parts of sea fish first brought to land (by
the catching or another vessel) outside the United Kingdom and only later
imported into the United Kingdom (in the same form or in the form of some other
fish product); and, secondly, if it does, whether the imposition of any such levy
was and is a charge equivalent to a customs duty, contrary to articles 28 and 30 of
the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (“TFEU”), in so far as it
applies to imports from other EU member states.
3. The respondents are importers who have brought these proceedings to
challenge the validity of levies made on them in respect of imports. The appellants
are the Department for Environment, Food and Rural Affairs, and the Authority,
having been a defendant in the proceedings, now appears as intervener. The
respondents’ challenge failed before Hamblen J [2009] EWHC 1721 (QB), but
succeeded in the Court of Appeal [2010] EWCA Civ 263, [2010] 1 WLR 2117.
Before the Supreme Court, they suggest that the second issue should also cover
imports from non-EU states and that consideration be given to a further issue
under article 110, if articles 28 and 30 do not apply. I will return to these
suggestions later in this judgment.
4. Section 14(2) defines the sea fish industry and persons engaged in it:
“… ‘the sea fish industry’ means the sea fish industry in the United
Kingdom and a person shall be regarded as engaged in the sea fish
industry if –
Page 3
(a) he carries on the business of operating vessels for catching or
processing sea fish or for transporting sea fish or sea fish products,
being vessels registered in the United Kingdom; or
(b) he carries on in the United Kingdom the business of breeding,
rearing or cultivating sea fish for human consumption, of selling sea
fish or sea fish products by wholesale or retail, of buying sea fish or
sea fish products by wholesale, of importing sea fish or sea fish
products or of processing sea fish (including the business of a fish
fryer).”
5. Section 4(3) to (5) state the bases upon which a levy may be imposed:
“(3) Regulations under this section may impose a levy either –
(a) in respect of the weight of sea fish or sea fish products landed in
the United Kingdom or trans-shipped within British fishery limits at
a prescribed rate which, in the case of sea fish, shall not exceed 2p
per kilogram; or
(b) in respect of the value, ascertained in the prescribed manner, of
sea fish or sea fish products landed or trans-shipped as aforesaid at a
prescribed rate not exceeding 1 per cent of that value.
(4) If regulations under this section impose a levy as provided in
subsection (3)(a) above the prescribed rate in relation to any sea fish
product shall be such that its yield will not in the opinion of the
Authority exceed the yield from a levy at the rate of 2p per kilogram
on the sea fish required on average (whether alone or together with
any other substance or article) to produce a kilogram of that product.
(5) Different rates may be prescribed for sea fish or sea fish products
of different descriptions; ….
…..
(8) For the purposes of this section –
Page 4
(a) parts of a sea fish shall be treated as sea fish products and not as
sea fish;
(b) references to the landing of fish include references to the
collection for consumption of sea fish which have been bred, reared
or cultivated in the course of fish farming whether in the sea or
otherwise and references to the landing of fish or fish products
include references to bringing them through the tunnel system as
defined in the Channel Tunnel Act 1987.”
The second part of section 4(8), referring to the landing of fish or fish products
through the Channel Tunnel, was inserted by the Channel Tunnel (Amendment of
the Fisheries Act 1981) Order 1994 (SI 1994/1390).
6. Section 2(2A) was inserted by the Fisheries Act 1981 (Amendment)
Regulations 1989 (SI 1989/1190) to cater for a concern raised by the European
Commission that the effect of the levy might be unduly to burden the sea fish
industries of other EU states to the benefit of the United Kingdom’s sea fish
industry:
“(2A) If any levy imposed under section 4 below has effect in
relation to sea fish or sea fish products from the sea fish industries of
member States other than the United Kingdom, the Authority shall
so exercise its powers under this Part of this Act as to secure that
benefits are conferred on those industries commensurate with any
burden directly or indirectly borne by them in consequence of the
levy.”
7. The regulations made by the Authority are currently the Sea Fish Industry
Authority (Levy) Regulations 1995 (“the 1995 Regulations”), as contained in the
Schedule to the Sea Fish Industry Authority (Levy) Regulations 1995
Confirmatory Order 1996 (SI 1996/160). They cover imports expressly:
“2. Interpretation
In these Regulations, unless the context otherwise requires, the
following expressions have the meanings hereby respectively
assigned to them –
….
Page 5
‘firsthand sale’ means –
(a) in relation to any sea fish or sea fish product which has been first
landed in the United Kingdom the first sale thereof (other than a sale
by retail) whether prior to or after landing in the United Kingdom;
(b) in relation to any sea fish or sea fish product which has been first
landed outside the United Kingdom and any sea fish product
manufactured outside the United Kingdom from such sea fish or sea
fish product which in either case is purchased by a person carrying
on business in the sea fish industry and is imported or brought into
the United Kingdom for the purposes of any such business, the first
sale thereof (whether in the United Kingdom or elsewhere) to such a
person as aforesaid;
(c) in relation to any sea fish or sea fish product which is transshipped within British fishery limits, the first sale thereof;…
‘sale by retail’ means a sale to a person buying otherwise than for the
purpose of resale or processing or use as bait, and includes a sale to a
person for the purposes of a catering business (other than a fish
frying business); and ‘sell by retail’ has a corresponding meaning; …
4. Imposition of levy
(1) There shall be paid to the Authority subject to and in accordance
with the provisions of these Regulations by every person engaged in
the sea fish industry who –
(a) purchases any sea fish or any sea fish product on a firsthand sale;
or
(b) trans-ships within British fishery limits any sea fish or any sea
fish product by way of firsthand sale; or
(c) lands any sea fish or sea fish product in the United Kingdom for
subsequent sale other than in the United Kingdom;
Page 6
a levy (hereinafter referred to as ‘the levy’) at the rate per kilogram
set out in the second column of the Schedule hereto in respect of any
sea fish or sea fish product specified opposite thereto in the first
column of the said Schedule so purchased or trans-shipped or landed
by him.
…..
(6) Where the levy becomes payable in respect of any sea fish it shall
not be payable in respect of the products of such sea fish.
5. Time Limits for Payment
(1) Levy payable by a person who purchases any sea fish or sea fish
product on a firsthand sale shall be paid to the Authority within
seven days after the end of –
(a) the week during which there took place the firsthand sale of the
fish or fish product in respect of which the levy is payable; or
(b) the week during which such fish or fish product was imported or
brought into the country;
whichever is the later.”
8. The Schedule to the Regulations contains rates of levy for sea fish and sea
fish products. There are ten different categories of sea fish products, starting with
“fresh, frozen or chilled sea fish”, under which different rates are set out for
“gutted”, “headless and gutted”, “fillets, skin on” and “fillets, skinless”.
Consistently with section 4(8) of the Act, parts of a sea fish are treated as sea fish
products. Other categories include “smoked sea fish”, again with different rates for
“headless and gutted”, “fillets, skin on” and “fillets, skinless”, “salted and cured
sea fish”, with different rates for wet and dried, “sea fish products sold for
fishmeal”, “sea fishmeal”, “any sea fish product not referred to above” and “any
pelagic fish product not referred to above”, each with a different rate. The different
rates reflect the usable fish content in the various sub-categories.
Page 7
The meaning of “landed”
9. The first issue is whether the statutory power enables a levy in respect of
sea fish or parts of sea fish first brought to land (by the catching or another vessel)
outside the United Kingdom and only later imported into the United Kingdom (in
the same form or in the form of some other fish product). The issue has, strictly, to
be formulated in these terms, because fish first landed in the United Kingdom from
a vessel not registered in the United Kingdom are under European Union law to be
regarded as imported. There is a choice between a wider and a narrower sense of
the word “landed” in section 4(3). The former would cover any form of bringing
into the United Kingdom, commonly by sea or air, wherever the sea fish or fish
product may have been first landed after catch. The latter would cover only their
first landing after catch. Hamblen J acknowledged that the narrower meaning was,
in many contexts, likely to have been intended, but considered that, in the specific
context of the 1981 Act, the wider meaning applied. Richards LJ, giving the only
full judgment in the Court of Appeal started with the provisional view that the
“normal” meaning did not cover the arrival of fish or fish product on a ferry or
aircraft from another country, and that it would be “highly artificial” to extend it to
their importation by road or rail as might occur between Eire and Northern Ireland.
He looked at the factors on which the judge had relied, and found none of them
sufficient to displace that view.
10. In matters of statutory construction, the statutory purpose and the general
scheme by which it is to be put into effect are of central importance. They
represent the context in which individual words are to be understood. In this area
as in the area of contractual construction, “the notion of words having a natural
meaning” is not always very helpful (Charter Reinsurance Co Ltd v Fagan [1997]
AC 313, 391C, per Lord Hoffmann), and certainly not as a starting point, before
identifying the legislative purpose and scheme. In the case of a statute which has,
like the 1981 Act, been the subject of amendment it is not lightly to be concluded
that Parliament, when making the amendment, misunderstood the general scheme
of the original legislation, with the effect of creating a palpable anomaly (see eg
the principle that provisions in a later Act in pari materia with an earlier may be
used to aid the construction of the former, discussed in Bennion on Statutory
Interpretation, 5th ed (2008), section 234).
11. The purpose and scheme of the 1981 Act are identified in sections 2(1) and
14(2). The Authority is set up and given powers to promote the efficiency of the
sea fish industry, and this is defined specifically to include importers of sea fish or
sea fish products. The purpose and scheme are expressed in terms extending to
importers generally. Yet the narrower sense of the word “landed” would mean that
very few of such importers actually contributed to the levy. Some of such
importers would be the operators of foreign fishing vessels who first landed their
fish in the United Kingdom, but the specific reference to importers in section 14(2)
Page 8
would be unnecessary to catch their fish, since (accepting that they would not
themselves be likely to be carrying on business in the United Kingdom) those who
purchased their fish would be covered by the reference in section 14(2) to buying
by wholesale or selling by retail.
12. Section 2(2A) is clearly intended to address a concern that the burden of the
levy would fall on those engaged in the sea fish industries of other EU member
states, while the benefits would accrue disproportionately to those engaged in the
United Kingdom’s sea fish industry. Such a situation would have involved an
obvious risk of infringement of European Union law, in the form currently of
TFEU article 110, considered below (see Case 73/79, Commission v Italy [1980]
ECR 1533) – that is the point that the European Commission had been making to
the United Kingdom government (para 6 above). Section 2(2A) is in terms which
suggest a general concern, whereas the narrower sense would eliminate any impact
on the sea fish industries of other member states, with the exception of the
catching sector.
13. The predecessor schemes to that introduced by the 1981 Act had all
involved levies imposed on imports. In particular, under the Sea Fish Industry Act
1970, the White Fish Authority was given power to impose a general levy on
persons engaged in the white fish industry in respect of white fish and white fish
products landed in the United Kingdom (section 17(1)(a)) and references to
persons so engaged were to “be construed as including references to persons
carrying on in Great Britain the business of buying the products of white fish by
wholesale or of importing white fish or their products” (section 17(8)). The
Authority had the general function of reorganising, developing and regulating the
white fish industry in Great Britain, having “regard to the interest of consumers in
a plentiful supply of white fish at reasonable prices, as well as to the interests of
the different sections of the white fish industry” (section 1(1), 4(1) and 27(1)), and
persons engaged and vessels used in the industry were required to be registered
(sections 8 and 9). For these purposes, a person was “without prejudice to section
17(8) ….. deemed to engage in the white fish industry if he carries on the business
of operating vessels to which this Part of the Act applies for catching or processing
white fish or for transporting white fish or the products of white fish, or if he
carries on in Great Britain the business of selling white fish by wholesale or by
retail or of processing white fish (including the business of a fish fryer)” (section
27(1)). The conjunction of section 17(1)(a) and section 17(8), which Richards LJ
did not mention, makes it impossible to suggest that the 1970 Act did not authorise
levies on imports. While the present Authority has no regulatory function, no
reason has been suggested for any change of policy under the 1981 Act as regards
the ambit of its promotional role or the source of its funding, so as largely to
exclude fish importations and importers.
Page 9
14. It is true that, in the 1981 Act, the reference to persons carrying on in the
United Kingdom the business of importing sea fish or sea fish products appears in
the interpretation section 14(2) at the end of Part I, rather than in section 2(1)
identifying the Authority’s duties or section 4 providing for levies. But that
drafting change is of no significance. The interpretation section defines the
meanings of the “sea fish industry” to which the duties imposed by section 2(1)
refer and of “persons engaged in the sea fish industry” on whom levies may be
imposed under section 4(1) and (2). It would be particularly surprising therefore if
the word “landed”, introduced in section 4(3) as the basis on which levies may be
imposed, had the effect that they could not be imposed at all on a large number of
imports.
15. Taking “landed” in its narrower sense, the reference to “sea fish products
landed in the United Kingdom” in section 4(3)(a) could in fact only apply to the
sea fish parts which result from the de-heading, gutting and filleting which occurs
on board catching or mother vessels and which are by section 4(8) to be treated as
sea fish products, rather than as sea fish. Yet section 4(8) is not framed as an
exclusive definition, and section 4(4) confirms that the concept of sea fish products
is intended to operate more widely. It refers expressly to sea fish products resulting
from the addition of other substances or articles to, or their admixture with, fish
parts.
16. Section 4(8), providing that landing includes bringing through the Channel
Tunnel, is also significant. Richards LJ accepted that, if the narrower sense of
“landed” otherwise applied, the specific provision relating to the Channel Tunnel
was a “striking anomaly”. However, he thought it no more than that, saying that it
could not have been intended to have any wider effect on the pre-existing statutory
language, that, if the wider meaning otherwise applied, then it was not necessary at
all and that, if the wider meaning had been otherwise intended, the natural place to
make this clear was section 4(8). To my mind these are unconvincing responses to
the discriminatory and on its face irrational distinction, between cross-Channel
imports by ferry or air and by the Tunnel, that results from the narrower sense of
the word “landed”.
17. First, it is clear that section 4(8) in its original form was introduced with a
clarificatory intent, to put beyond doubt, rather than because it was actually
necessary. The collection and bringing to shore of fish from a fish farm is an
activity which one would have thought was anyway embraced within the narrow
sense of the word “landed”. But I can understand the draftsman making this clear,
while at the same time assuming that there was no doubt about importations by
cross-Channel ferry or aircraft constituting “landing” in the United Kingdom.
Page 10
18. Secondly, the Channel Tunnel was in 1994 the first “land” link to the rest of
the Continent. One can understand that those responsible for introducing
legislation necessary to cater for this new phenomenon might wonder whether
goods that remained on (or under) land throughout a Channel crossing could be
regarded as “landed”, and might decide to put that beyond doubt. It is
inconceivable that they intended or thought to introduce a striking anomaly or to
ensure anything other than a coherent scheme. It is not surprising that they did not
cater expressly for cross-Channel importations by ferry or air: their remit was no
doubt to cater for the Channel Tunnel and their starting point must have been that
such importations were already embraced by the word “landed”. As to the
possibility of land importations of fish or fish products across the border from Eire
to Northern Ireland, if the original draftsman of the 1981 Act intended the wider
sense of “landed” and directed his or her mind to that possibility at all, he or she
must have assumed that the wider meaning of “landed” would cover it. It is again
understandable if those concerned with ensuring that the Channel Tunnel was
covered by appropriate legislation did not direct their minds to that specific border.
19. Most of these points were covered in the judge’s very clear judgment. The
Court of Appeal’s approach does not in my view give due weight to the legislative
purpose and scheme as a whole, having particular regard to the definition of
“persons engaged in the sea fish industry” which relates to the Authority’s duties
and powers, including its power to levy. Viewed in this context, the word
“landed”, used as a measure of the levies which can be applied, is capable of
covering and, to make sense of the legislative purpose and scheme, should be read
as covering all sorts of arrival of sea fish and sea fish products in the United
Kingdom. The striking anomaly which would otherwise result from the provision
catering for the Channel Tunnel is further confirmation of this conclusion.
20. It is in the circumstances unnecessary to address the detailed submissions
made by the parties on the admissibility of various exchanges which took place in
Parliament during the passage of the 1981 Act as reported in Hansard. A primary
issue here was, assuming the relevant provisions to be at least ambiguous, whether
and how far it is legitimate to apply the rule in Pepper v Hart [1993] AC 593 to
give rise to an expanded power to impose a levy, rather than to narrow executive
power. It is not necessary or appropriate to go further into that issue in this case.
The wider view of the word “landed” is, I consider, plainly correct. Suffice it to
say, that, had it been appropriate to have regard to Hansard, the ministerial
statements in response to specific questions in the course of the Bill’s passage
through Parliament would in my view have confirmed very clearly that it was
intended, by section 14(2), to maintain the pre-existing levying power in relation to
imports generally.
21. The Court of Appeal’s conclusions on European Union law led it to add that
a narrow interpretation of the word “landed” was in any event required to avoid
Page 11
incompatibility with European Union law: Case 106/89 Marleasing SA v La
Comercial Internacional de Alimentación SA [1991] ECR I-4135. For reasons
which will appear in the next section of this judgment, I do not agree with the
Court of Appeal’s conclusion on European Union law. But, even if I had done, I
would not have considered them to require a narrow interpretation of “landed”.
The wider meaning would have been compatible with the making of regulations
which complied with European Union law. The incompatibility would have
affected the validity of the present regulations, not the interpretation of the 1981
Act.
A charge having equivalent effect to customs duty (“CEE”)?
(a) The law
22. The second issue which arises in the light of my conclusion on the first
issue is whether the levy constitutes a charge having equivalent effect to customs
duty (a “CEE”) in respect of imports of sea fish or sea fish products from other
member states of the European Union, contrary to TFEU articles 28 and 30. If it is
a CEE, then it is in relation to such imports void. If it is not, it may fall to be
considered as an internal tax or due within article 110, in which case it will be
valid except to the extent that it may be held to be discriminatory in relation to
imports from other member states.
23. The articles to which I have referred provide as follows:
“PART 3 UNION POLICIES AND INTERNAL ACTIONS
TITLE II – FREE MOVEMENT OF GOODS
Article 28
The Union shall comprise a customs union which shall cover all
trade in goods and which shall involve the prohibition between
Member States of customs duties on imports and exports and of all
charges having equivalent effect, and the adoption of a common
customs tariff in their relations with third countries.
…….
Page 12
CHAPTER 1
THE CUSTOMS UNION
Article 30
Customs duties on imports and exports and charges having
equivalent effect shall be prohibited between Member States. This
prohibition shall also apply to customs duties of a fiscal nature.
……
TITLE VII – COMMON RULES ON COMPETITION.
TAXATION AND APPROXIMATION OF LAWS
Article 110
No Member State shall impose, directly or indirectly, on the products
of other Member States any internal taxation of any kind in excess of
that imposed directly or indirectly on similar domestic products.
Furthermore, no Member State shall impose on the products of other
Member States any internal taxation of such a nature as to afford
indirect protection to other products.”
24. The distinction between a CEE within articles 28 and 30 and a tax within
article 110 is clear cut in principle. The two are alternatives, and a levy must fall
into one category or the other. It cannot fall into both. But it is not always easy in
practice to decide into which category a levy does fall. The distinction, though
clear cut, can be very fine. So Advocate General Jacobs observed in Case C-90/94
Haahr Petroleum Ltd v Åbenrå Havn [1997] ECR I-4085, para 38 and again in
Case C-213/96 Proceedings brought by Outokumpu Oy [1998] ECR I-1777, para
15. The underlying objective is the same, to avoid discrimination against goods
from other member states, and overlapping considerations apply in relation to
each.
25. However, it is clear that a charge may be within the scope of and in breach
of article 110 without this meaning that it is or becomes a CEE prohibited under
Page 13
articles 28 and 30: see eg Case 32/80 Officier van Justitie v Kortmann [1981] ECR
251, para 18 (which reads more intelligibly in the French), Haahr, paras 25-44 and
Joined Cases C-78/90 to C-83/90 Compagnie commerciale de l’Ouest v Receveur
principal des douanes de La Pallice-Port [1992] ECR I-1847, discussed below.
There are thus different stages at which a question of prohibited discrimination
may arise; one is where a charge constitutes a CEE, the other is where it does not
constitute a CEE but is part of a general system of internal dues organised in a
manner which discriminates against products originating in another member state.
26. The principal feature of a CEE is that it is levied solely or exclusively by
reason of goods crossing the frontier, whereas domestic products are excluded
from similar charge. Internal taxation within article 110 falls in contrast on both
imported and domestic products: Case 78/76 Firma Steinike und Weinlig v
Germany [1977] ECR 595, paras 28-29, Case 32/80 Officier van Justitie v
Kortmann [1981] ECR 251, para 18 and Outokumpu, para 27. However, a charge
may be regarded as levied solely or exclusively by reason of its crossing the
frontier, although it is applied at a later stage, such as marketing or processing of
the product: Steinike, para 29.
27. The Court amplified the distinction as follows in Steinike:
“28….. the prohibition [of a CEE] is aimed at any tax demanded at
the time of or by reason of importation and which, being imposed
specifically on an imported product to the exclusion of a similar
domestic product, results in the same restrictive consequences on the
free movement of goods as a customs duty by altering the cost price
of that product. The essential characteristic of a charge having an
effect equivalent to a customs duty, which distinguishes it from
internal taxation, is that the first is imposed exclusively on the
imported product whilst the second is imposed on both imported and
domestic products. A charge affecting both imported products and
similar products could however constitute a charge having an effect
equivalent to a customs duty if such a duty, which is limited to
particular products, had the sole purpose of financing activities for
the specific advantage of the taxed domestic products, so as to make
good, wholly or in part, the fiscal charge imposed upon them”.
28. The last sentence (not directly relevant on the present appeal and deriving
originally from Case 77/72 Capolongo v Maya [1973] ECR 611) needs to be read
with the fuller explanation or qualification given in the later Joined Cases C-78/90
to C-83/90 Compagnie commerciale de l’Ouest v Receveur principal des douanes
de La Pallice-Port [1992] ECR I-1847:
Page 14
“26 Where a charge is imposed on domestic and imported products
according to the same criteria, the Court has nevertheless stated that
it may be necessary to take into account the purpose to which the
revenue from the charge is put. Thus, if the revenue from such a
charge is intended to finance activities for the special advantage of
the taxed domestic product, it may follow that the charge imposed on
the basis of the same criteria nevertheless constitutes discriminatory
taxation in so far as the fiscal burden on the domestic products is
neutralized by the advantages which the charge is used to finance
whilst the charge on the imported product constitutes a net burden
(judgment in Case 73/79 Commission v Italy [1980] ECR 1533, para
15).
27 It follows from the foregoing considerations that if the advantages
stemming from the use of the proceeds of the charge in question
fully offset the burden borne by the domestic product when it is
placed on the market, that charge constitutes a charge having an
effect equivalent to customs duties, contrary to article 12 [now 30] et
seq of the Treaty. If, on the other hand, those advantages only partly
offset the burden borne by domestic products, the charge in question
is subject to article 95 [now 110] of the Treaty. In the latter case, the
charge would be incompatible with article 95 [110] of the Treaty and
is therefore prohibited to the extent to which it discriminates against
imported products, that is to say to the extent to which it partially
offsets the burden borne by the taxed domestic product.”
29. This explanation helps to point the differing spheres of operation of a CEE
prohibited under articles 28 and 30 and an internal, but none the less
discriminatory, tax falling within article 110. In the present case, the respondents
did in their pre-trial skeleton argument seek to raise a case that the levy amounted
to a CEE because its benefits went exclusively to domestic sea fish and products,
or alternatively that it infringed article 110 because the latter derived
proportionately greater benefit than imported sea fish and products. This case
raised factual issues which the judge ruled could not be dealt with at the trial.
However, by post-trial order dated 24 July 2009, I understand that he ultimately
permitted them to be raised by amendment as a separate issue for subsequent trial.
30. A charge levied by reason of goods crossing a frontier will not be regarded
as a CEE “if it forms part of a general system of internal dues applied
systematically to categories of products according to objective criteria applied
without regard to the origin of the products”. This or a close approximation is the
formulation used in a large number of authorities from Case C-90/79 Commission
v France [1981] ECR 283 to Case C-314/82 Commission v Belgium [1984] ECR
1543, paras 11, 13 and 19, Case C-90/94 Haahr Petroleum Ltd v Åbenrå Havn,
Page 15
above, para 20, Case C-213/96 Outokumpu, above, para 20, Case C-234/99 Nygård
v Svineafgiftsfonden [2002] ECR I-3657, para 29 and Case C-387/01 Weigel v
Finanzlandesdirektion für Vorarlberg [2004] ECR I-4951, para 64. Another way
of analysing the position may be that, if a charge forms part of a general system of
internal dues meeting these conditions, then it is not imposed solely by reason of
the goods crossing the frontier.
31. If a charge forms part of such a general system of internal dues, any
suggestion of discrimination will fall to be considered under article 110. The Court
said in Steinike, para 30, that:
“The objective of article 95 [now 110] is to abolish direct or indirect
discrimination against imported products but not to place them in a
privileged tax position in relation to domestic products. There is
generally no discrimination such as is prohibited by article 95 [110]
where internal taxation applies to domestic products and to
previously imported products on their being processed into more
elaborate products without any distinctions of rate, basis of
assessment or detailed rules for the levying thereof being made
between them by reason of their origin.”
32. As an example, in Haahr a 40% import surcharge imposed on goods
imported into Denmark by ship from other member states was held not to be a
CEE. Rather it was (as a surcharge) an integral part of a general system of internal
dues for the use of commercial ports and their facilities “imposed on goods, both
domestic and imported, at the same time and in accordance with the same
objective criteria, namely when they are taken on board or put ashore and
according to the type of goods and their weight” (paras 21-24); and, as a result:
“the fact that the import surcharge is payable ex hypothesi solely on
imported goods and that the origin of the goods determines the
amount of the duty to be levied cannot remove the tax in general or
the surcharge in particular from the scope of article 95 [now 110] of
the Treaty; accordingly, their compatibility with Community law
must be assessed in the light of that provision and not articles 9 to 13
[now 28 to 31] of the Treaty”
The Court went on (in para 27) to refer to the issue of discrimination that can arise
under article 110, saying:
Page 16
“It is ….. beyond question that application of a higher charge to
imported products than to domestic products or application to
imported products alone of a surcharge in addition to the duty
payable on domestic and imported products is contrary to the
prohibition of discrimination laid down in article 95 [now 110].”
33. The respondents rely upon statements from another case, important in the
development of the case-law under what are now articles 28 and 30 and pre-dating
those cited in paragraph 29 above: Case 132/78 Denkavit Loire Sàrl v France
[1979] ECR 1923. The Court there explained the criteria identifying a CEE, and
distinguished a CEE from an internal tax within article 110, using somewhat
different wording. The respondents suggest that this wording establishes a need for
identical treatment of imported and other goods in every relevant respect, before a
levy will avoid being categorised as a CEE.
34. In particular, the Court in Denkavit referred to systematic application “in
accordance with the same criteria to domestic products and imported products
alike” (para 7) and continued (para 8):
“It is however appropriate to emphasise that in order to relate to a
general system of internal dues, the charge to which an imported
product is subject must impose the same duty on national products
and identical imported products at the same marketing stage and that
the chargeable event giving rise to the duty must also be identical in
the case of both products. It is therefore not sufficient that the
objective of the charge imposed on imported products is to
compensate for a charge imposed on similar domestic products – or
which has been imposed on those products or a product from which
they are derived – at a production or marketing stage prior to that at
which the imported products are taxed. To exempt a charge levied at
the frontier from the classification of a charge having equivalent
effect when it is not imposed on similar national products or is
imposed on them at different marketing stages or, again, on the basis
of a different chargeable event giving rise to duty, because that
charge aims to compensate for a domestic fiscal charge applying to
the same products – apart from the fact that this would not take into
account fiscal charges which had been imposed on imported
products in the originating Member State – would make the
prohibition on charges having an effect equivalent to customs duties
empty and meaningless.”
The requirements set out in the first sentence of para 8 in Denkavit have
themselves been echoed in a number of cases, including Joined Cases C-149/91
Page 17
and C-150/91 Sanders Adour Snc v Directeur des Services Fiscaux des PyrénéesAtlantiques [1992] ECR I-3899 at para 17, Outokumpu at para 24, Joined Cases C441/98 and C-442/98 Kapniki Mikhailidis AE v Idryma Kinonikon Asphaliseon
[2000] ECR I-7145 and Nygård at para 20.
35. The same requirements have however been given a generous interpretation.
In Sanders the Court said (para 18):
“As to the requirement that the chargeable events be identical, no
difference may be discerned in the present case in the fact that the
charge is levied on an imported product at the time of importation
and on the domestic product when it is sold or used, for in actual
economic terms the marketing stage is the same since both
operations are carried out with a view to utilisation of the product.”
36. In Outokumpu the Court treated a duty on electricity as forming part of a
general system of taxation (and so within article 110, rather than the equivalents of
articles 28 and 30) although it was “levied not only on electrical energy as such but
also on several primary energy sources such as coal products, peat, natural gas and
pine oil” (para 21). The duty was levied on these primary sources, on electricity
produced from other sources domestically and on imported electricity, and the
Court, citing Sanders, para 18, said at para 25 that:
“…. in circumstances such as those of this case, no difference may
be discerned in the fact that imported electricity is taxed at the time
of importation and electricity of domestic origin at the time of
production, since in view of the characteristics of electricity the
marketing stage is the same for both operations, namely the stage
when the electricity enters the national distribution network ….”.
37. In the same case, at para 30, Advocate General Francis Jacobs QC noted
that in previous decisions the Court had accepted that a tax on the wort used in
making beer domestically and a tax on imported beer adjusted to take account of
the notional amount of wort used in its overseas production fell within article 110,
rather than the equivalents of articles 28 and 30: Case 152/89 Commission v
Luxembourg [1991] ECR I-3141 and Case 153/89 Commission v Belgium [1991]
ECR I-3171.
38. In Nygård the Court held that a levy on pigs sent for slaughter on the
domestic market and exported live to other member states satisfied similarly stated
requirements. Citing Sanders, para 18, and Outokumpu, para 25, it said that:
Page 18
“29. …. the event giving rise to the levy here in issue in the main
proceedings must be considered to be the withdrawal of the pigs
from the national herd, regardless of whether that levy is charged on
pigs intended for slaughter in Denmark or for live export. In both
cases, therefore, the fiscal obligation arises when the animals leave
the primary national production.
30 In those circumstances, no difference may be discerned in the fact
that pigs exported live are taxed at the time of exportation, whereas
pigs intended for slaughter on the national market are taxed at the
time of supply for purposes of slaughter, as in real economic terms
those two moments correspond to the same marketing stage, both
operations being carried out with a view to releasing the pigs from
national primary production …..”
39. The approach in these cases is consistent with that taken in the earlier case
of Case 90/79 Commission v France [1981] ECR 283, where the Court addressed
the situation of a French levy on sales and appropriations for own use, other than
for export, of reprographic machines, in circumstances where 99% of such
machines were imported. The Court said (para 14) that:
“…. even a charge which is borne by a product imported from
another Member State, when there is no identical or similar domestic
product, does not constitute a charge having equivalent effect but
internal taxation within the meaning of article 95 of the Treaty if it
relates to a general system of internal dues applied systematically to
categories of products in accordance with objective criteria
irrespective of the origin of the products.”
It went on to treat the levy as internal taxation because its purpose was to redress
the inequity resulting from the copying of published material, which would, if sold
and bought in published form, have attracted a levy, and because it could be
regarded as part of the same internal system of taxation as that levy:
“16 The Court is of the opinion that the particular features of the
levy in issue lead to its being accepted as forming part of such a
general system of internal dues. That follows first from its inclusion
in taxation arrangements which have their origin in the breach made
in legal systems for the protection of copyright by the increase in the
use of reprography and which are designed to subject, if only
indirectly, the users of those processes to a charge which
compensates for that which they would normally have to bear.
Page 19
17 That conclusion follows in the second place from the fact that the
levy in issue forms a single entity with the levy imposed on book
publishers by the same internal legislation and from the fact, too, that
it is borne by a range of very different machines which are moreover
classified under various customs headings but which have in
common the fact that they are all intended to be used for
reprographic purposes in addition to more specific uses.”
(b) Application of the law to this case
40. Applying the guidance given in these authorities to the present case, the
first question is whether the regulations impose any levy on sea fish and sea fish
products by reason of their crossing a frontier within the European Union. In
Weigel the Court held that a tax imposed on the registration of second-hand
vehicles, as well as vehicles sold and hired out for the first time for use on the
road, was not, in the case of an imported second-hand car, imposed by reason of its
import, but by reason of the need to register it. In the present case, however, the
levy is expressly authorised to be imposed on importers in respect of sea fish and
sea fish products landed (accepting, as I do, the wider sense) from other member
states, after first landing outside the United Kingdom. The consideration that,
under regulation 5, a firsthand sale is also required as the trigger for a chargeable
event does not alter the fact that the levy is imposed by reason of the import: see
Steinike, para 29, cited above.
41. That does not conclude the matter, or mean that the levy is imposed solely
or exclusively by reason of the import, in particular if the levy “forms part of a
general system of internal dues applied systematically to categories of products
according to objective criteria applied without regard to the origin of the
products”, or, to the extent that this differs, meets the generously interpreted
requirements that it “impose[s] the same duty on national products and identical
imported products at the same marketing stage and that the chargeable event
giving rise to the duty must also be identical in the case of both products”: see
paras 30 to 39 above.
42. On this, Richards LJ said:
“55. In purely formal terms the 1995 Regulations appear to meet
those requirements. They lay down a uniform system that draws no
distinction between domestic and imported products as regards rates
of levy, production or marketing stage or chargeable event. The
authorities make clear, however, that one must look beyond form and
examine contents and effects. It is here that, in my judgment, the
Page 20
scheme runs into difficulties in relation to sea fish products that have
been processed on land. By virtue of regulation 4(1)(a), a levy is
payable by a person who purchases a sea fish product on a firsthand
sale. That takes one to the definition of firsthand sale in regulation 2.
Imported products are covered by paragraph (b) of that definition,
the application of which will in practice generally produce a liability
to levy, since there will be both an importation and a first sale of the
products to a relevant person. Domestic products are covered by
paragraph (a) of the definition, but the application of that paragraph
will in practice produce no liability to levy. That is because liability
arises only in relation to sea fish products which have been “first
landed” in the United Kingdom; but products resulting from
processing on land are in no sense “landed”, let alone “first landed”,
in the United Kingdom. The sea fish or sea fish product ingredients
from which they are produced may have been first landed in the
United Kingdom, but the resulting products are not.
56. In practice, therefore, the 1995 Regulations involve a material
difference of treatment between domestic and imported products.
…..”
43. This reasoning compares the levy payable on fish products imported into
and bought by an importer, wholesaler or retailer carrying on business in the
United Kingdom with the levy which it is assumed is not payable in respect of sea
fish products which are both manufactured and sold in the United Kingdom.
However, sea fish products which are imported into and sold in the United
Kingdom will be subject, in accordance with section 4(4) of the Act and the
regulations, to a levy which will reflect their sea fish content. If sea fish products
are manufactured in the United Kingdom from sea fish or sea fish products first
landed in the United Kingdom which have themselves been the subject of a
firsthand sale (or either of the other two levy-triggering events identified in
regulation 4(1)), the sea fish content of the subsequently manufactured sea fish
products will have borne the levy, as a result of its imposition on the sea fish or sea
fish products used in their manufacture. Regulation 4(6) confirms that the
manufactured sea fish products cannot themselves attract the levy on any sale. But
the reverse implication from regulation 4(6) is that, if sea fish products are
manufactured in the United Kingdom from sea fish or sea fish products first landed
in the United Kingdom which have not themselves been the subject of a firsthand
sale (or either of the other two levy-triggering events identified in regulation 4(1)),
then the subsequently manufactured sea fish products will bear the levy according
to their sea fish content. The manufactured sea fish products must in this
connection be equated with the sea fish or sea fish products from which they were
manufactured.
Page 21
44. The wording of the regulations is not perfect, but they must be read as
intended to introduce a coherent scheme. It cannot have been intended that sea fish
products manufactured in the United Kingdom from sea fish or sea fish products
first landed in the United Kingdom which have not themselves been the subject of
levy should escape the levy. This conclusion could, if it were necessary, also be
reinforced by the consideration that, if the regulations would otherwise involve
what would be a CEE favouring certain domestic producers as opposed to
importers (as the Court of Appeal thought), then this too cannot have been
intended, and the regulations should not be interpreted in this sense: Case 106/89
Marleasing SA v La Comercial Internacional de Alimentación SA [1991] 1 ECR
4135.
45. Even on such an analysis, it appears that Richards LJ may have considered
that the levy would constitute a CEE since it would involve the imposition of
charges at differing production or marketing stages, which is impermissible
although their effect is to compensate or balance each other. I say appears, because
a later comment in para 60 of his judgment (to which I will revert) leaves room for
doubt. On the other hand, he was not impressed by submissions that the scheme
involved different chargeable events or higher rates on imported than domestic
products (para 62).
46. As to the imposition of the levy at differing production or marketing stages,
Richards LJ relied upon Denkavit and Kapniki. In Denkavit the impugned tax was
payable on lard and other pig fat produced by rendering or solvent-extracted. The
only relevant domestic charge was levied on slaughter. The Court said that a
charge was a CEE, when it is imposed on imported goods, “even though no charge
is imposed on similar domestic products” or “according to different criteria, in
particular by reason of a different chargeable event”. In Kapniki a special
contribution (to go towards pensions and compensation payable to tobacco
workers) was charged on unprocessed tobacco exported from Greece. A
preliminary ruling was sought on the basis that no equivalent contribution was
levied on either imports or domestic products distributed in the home market, and
it was unclear that any other tax on tobacco existed in any form at the relevant
times, apart from VAT and excise duties on the retail consumption of processed
tobacco. Not surprisingly, the Court expressed serious doubts as to whether the
special contribution matched any comparable charge levied on domestic products
at the same rate and marketing stage and on the basis of an identical chargeable
event, while emphasising that it was “for the national court alone to determine the
exact effect of the national legislative provisions at issue” (para 25).
47. In contrast to the position in these cases, the present scheme identifies,
according to objective criteria, the time when sea fish or sea fish products can be
said to enter the United Kingdom market on a commercial basis, following upon
their production or importation and firsthand sale (in whichever order these events
Page 22
occur). In effect, it is as the judge said (para 125) “imposed when the sea fish is
placed on the market and enters the supply chain”. As the judge went on to note:
“the rate of levy paid on processed and unprocessed fish is proportionately the
same”, since the rate of levy rises according to the proportion of inedible parts
removed by processing, and (one can add) is adjusted to leave out of account “any
other substance or article” added to or mixed with sea fish parts to make a sea fish
product – these being the requirements of section 4(4).
48. If a general system of taxation within article 110 covers a tax on wort used
in domestic production and a tax on beer reflecting the wort assessed as to have
been used in the overseas production of imported beer (see para 37 above), that
points strongly to the present scheme falling within article 110, rather than
involving any CEE. If, as in Outokumpu (para 36 above), an internal system of
taxation within article 110 may embrace not only electricity imported and
electricity produced domestically, but also a levy “not only on electrical energy as
such but also on several primary energy sources such as coal products, peat,
natural gas and pine oil” (para 21), then such a system must be well capable of
embracing the present scheme. So too, if, as in Commission v France (para 39
above), a levy on the sale or appropriation for use (other than for export)
constitutes part of such an internal system, and a fortiori when the Court’s analysis
was that the levy “forms a single entity [“forme un ensemble”] with the levy
imposed on book publishers”.
49. Like both the judge (and in this respect it seems also the Court of Appeal:
para 62), I am also unable to accept that the chargeable events under the present
scheme operate upon materially different bases, where, as here, the difference is as
to whether the levy attaches on import or sale, but “in actual economic terms the
marketing stage is the same since both operations are carried out with a view to
utilisation of the product”: see Sanders, para 18 (para 35 above). Arguments that
the judge wrongly took the actual levies on domestic and imported sea fish or sea
fish products as equating with each other were barely if at all raised, and I reject
them both on the ground of the judge’s contrary finding and in any event. I also
doubt if they have any relevance under articles 28 and 30, as opposed to article
110.
50. It follows that I have no doubt that the present carefully structured scheme
falls to be regarded as “a general system of internal dues applied systematically to
categories of products according to objective criteria applied without regard to the
origin of the products” within the requirements of the case-law set out in paras 26,
30 and 33-34 above. It falls therefore within the scope of article 110, rather than
constituting a CEE under articles 28 and 30. It also appears from para 60 of
Richards LJ’s judgment that the Court of Appeal might itself have reached this
conclusion, but for its view that sea fish products manufactured in the United
Kingdom where there had been no sale of (or therefore levy on) either the sea fish
Page 23
or the sea fish products from which they were manufactured, escape all levy. I
have already indicated my disagreement with that view (paras 43-44 above).
51. The respondents suggested that, unless the appeal was dismissed, there
should, before its resolution, be a preliminary reference to the Court of Justice
under TFEU article 267. The Court of Justice has however established the
principles in a large number of authorities, including those which I have examined,
in a manner which enables its resolution. As the Court has stressed, it is for
national courts to apply such principles to particular facts – even in cases as
apparently unpromising from the national government’s viewpoint as Kapniki
(para 46 above). The Court of Justice’s role is one of interpretation, the national
court’s one of application. There is no need to refer any question of principle to the
Court of Justice in order to resolve this appeal. This is despite the Court of
Appeal’s differing conclusion as to the outcome, which in any event appears, as I
have said (paras 43-45 and 50 above), to have revolved substantially if not entirely
around a point of construction of the domestic regulations.
Additional points
52. Before the Supreme Court, the respondents sought to raise two additional
points. The first is that the prohibition of any CEE applies not merely to imports
from other member states of the European Union, but to imports from other states
“in particular where a common customs tariff applies in respect of those products
and there is a Cooperation Agreement between the EU and the countries from
which the products are imported”. This is a new point. It is one which cannot arise
in view of my conclusion that the levy does not impose a CEE within articles 28
and 30, and I need say no more than that. But I would add that it would have
involved enquiries, eg as to the existence and dates of entry into force of any
relevant common customs tariffs and Cooperation Agreements (see eg Case C126/94 Société Cadi Surgelés v Ministre des Finances [1996] ECR I-5647). This
would in my view have made it in any event inappropriate to entertain it for the
first time on this appeal.
53. The second is that, if article 110 applies, then the levy imposed taxation in
excess of that imposed on similar domestic products. The respondents’ wish is, in
other words, to argue a point along the lines contemplated in Steinike, para 30
(para 31 above) and in Haahr (para 32 above) to the effect that, although the levy
was part of a general system of internal taxation, it involved “distinctions of rate,
basis of assessment or detailed rules for the levying thereof being made” on
imported sea fish or sea fish product “by reason of their origin.” This is also a new
point, not covered by the judgment below or, so far as one can judge, by the
permission to amend given by the judge on 29 June 2009, and it is also not one
which this Court should now entertain.
Page 24
Conclusion
54. I would allow the appeal and make such orders as are appropriate to restore
the judge’s judgment dismissing the respondents’ claim and allow the Authority’s
counterclaim for levy and otherwise.
LORD PHILLIPS
55. I agree with the judgment of Lord Mance on each of the issues that arise on
this appeal. The first is one of statutory interpretation and I wish to add some
comments on this, because there is one feature of this case which is unusual, and
which should not pass unnoticed.
56. The issue of interpretation turns on the meaning to be attached to “landed in
the United Kingdom” in section 4(3)(a) of the Fisheries Act 1981. Does this mean
brought ashore for the first time in the United Kingdom (“the narrow meaning”),
or does its meaning extend to embrace bringing onto the territory of the United
Kingdom, whether directly from the sea or indirectly after having been brought
ashore in another country (“the broad meaning”)?
57. The unusual feature is that for nearly thirty years everyone concerned has
proceeded on the basis that the phrase should be given the broad meaning. Thus
the levy has been imposed and paid not only on fish and fish products brought
ashore for the first time in the United Kingdom, but fish and fish products
imported into the United Kingdom from other countries. The funds raised by the
levy have been disbursed in payment for schemes intended to benefit the sea fish
industry, which includes those whose business involves importing sea fish or sea
fish products from other countries. By the time that these proceedings were
commenced some 75% of the levy income was derived from imports. If the
decision of the Court of Appeal is correct, the activities of the Authority must be
drastically curtailed. Indeed, I would expect that the impact of potential claims for
reimbursement of monies wrongfully levied would render the Authority insolvent.
58. In circumstances such as these there must be, at the very least, a powerful
presumption that the meaning that has customarily been given to the phrase in
issue is the correct one. Carnwath LJ expressed one reason for this in Isle of
Anglesey County Council v Welsh Ministers [2009] EWCA Civ 94, [2010] QB
163:
Page 25
“Where an Act has been interpreted in a particular way without
dissent over a long period, those interested should be able to
continue to order their affairs on that basis without the risk of being
upset by a novel approach.”
59. This has the air of pragmatism rather than principle, but courts are
understandably reluctant to disturb a settled construction and the practice that has
been based on that construction- see Bennion on Statutory Interpretation, 5th ed
(2008), section 288 at p 913 and the authorities there cited.
60. A more principled justification for the principle is that of contemporaneous
exposition. Thus in Clyde Navigation (Trustees of) v Laird & Sons (1883) 8 App
Cas 658 the issue was whether the Clyde Navigation Consolidation Act 1858
required dues to be paid on logs which were chained together and floated down the
River Clyde. The evidence was that these dues had been levied and paid without
protest for a quarter of a century. Lord Blackburn commented at p 670 that this
raised a strong prima facie ground for thinking that there must exist some legal
ground for exacting the dues. Lord Watson at p 673 did not, however, agree with
this approach.
61. An important element in the construction of a provision in a statute is the
context in which that provision was enacted. It is plain that those affected by the
statute when it comes into force are better placed to appreciate that context than
those subject to it thirty years later. The 1981 Act was introduced as a successor to
legislation of similar character dating back to 1935. I would not readily have been
persuaded that those who, when the 1981 Act came into force, charged and paid
levies on imports of fish and fish products had misunderstood the effect of the Act.
62. The Court of Appeal reached this conclusion, however, on the basis of a
narrow textual analysis that was, in my view, flawed and which produced a
number of anomalies.
63. The textual analysis was flawed because it was dictated by the concept of
landing a fish, which does indeed naturally suggest the bringing of the fish ashore
for the first time. It did not, however, give proper weight to the fact that the
landing referred to was not just of sea fish but of sea fish products. While these
included “parts of sea fish” it was not suggested, nor sensibly could it have been,
that sea fish products were confined to parts of sea fish. As soon as one applies the
meaning of “landed in the United Kingdom” to “products” the natural conclusion
is that these must include products produced from fish brought ashore in countries
other than the United Kingdom, so that landed must bear the broader meaning.
Page 26
64. The anomalies produced by giving “landed” the narrow meaning are twofold. The first is that it produces a disparity between those who contribute to the
levy and those who benefit from it. Those who carry on the business of importing
sea fish or sea fish products are included in those for whose benefit the funds
raised by the levy are used (see sections 2(1) and 14 (2)), but do not have to
contribute to it.
65. The second anomaly, recognised by Richards LJ, relates to the amendment
made to section 4(8) by the Channel Tunnel (Amendment of the Fisheries Act
1981) Order 1994 (SI 1994/1390). If “landed” means brought ashore for the first
time it is a nonsense to extend its meaning to cover sea fish or fish products
brought into the United Kingdom through the Channel Tunnel.
66. Hamblen J referred to the principle that the meaning and effect of an
amended statute should generally be ascertained by an examination of the
language of that statute as amended (Inco Europe Ltd v First Choice Distribution
[1999] 1 WLR 270, 272-273). I do not think that that is the correct approach in this
case. Had it been right to interpret “landed” as bearing the narrow meaning before
this amendment was made, I do not consider that it would have been right to treat
this amendment as altering the overall interpretation of the Act so as to give
“landed” the broad meaning. The amendment was peripheral to the Act as a whole
and it would not have been right to allow the tail (the amendment) to wag the dog
(the Act). The significance of the amendment is that it reflects the accepted
meaning given by everybody, including Parliament, to the meaning of “landed”. It
thus reinforces the principle that I have identified at paras 58 to 61 above. The
same point applies to the insertion of section 2(2A) by the Fisheries Act 1981
(Amendment) Regulations 1989.
67. It is for these reasons that I agree with the conclusions of Lord Mance in
relation to the first issue. I have nothing to add to his analysis in respect of the
second issue. Accordingly I would allow this appeal.